Wealthiest Hospitals Got Billions in Bailout for Struggling Health Providers
Twenty large chains received more than $5 billion in federal grants even while sitting on more than $100 billion in cash.
A multibillion-dollar institution in the Seattle area invests in
hedge funds, runs a pair of venture capital funds and works with elite
private equity firms like the Carlyle Group.
But it is
not just another deep-pocketed investor hunting for high returns. It is
the Providence Health System, one of the country’s largest and richest
hospital chains. It is sitting on nearly $12 billion in cash, which it
invests, Wall Street-style, in a good year generating more than $1
billion in profits.
And this spring, Providence
received at least $509 million in government funds, one of many wealthy
beneficiaries of a federal program that is supposed to prevent health
care providers from capsizing during the coronavirus pandemic.
With
states restricting hospitals from performing elective surgery and other
nonessential services, their revenue has shriveled. The Department of
Health and Human Services has disbursed $72 billion in grants since
April to hospitals and other health care providers through the bailout
program, which was part of the CARES Act economic stimulus package. The
department plans to eventually distribute more than $100 billion more.
So
far, the riches are flowing in large part to hospitals that had already
built up deep financial reserves to help them withstand an economic
storm. Smaller, poorer hospitals are receiving tiny amounts of federal
aid by comparison.
Twenty large recipients, including Providence, have received a total of more than $5 billion in recent weeks, according to an analysis of federal data
by Good Jobs First, a research group. Those hospital chains were
already sitting on more than $108 billion in cash, according to
regulatory filings and the bond-rating firms S&P Global and Fitch. A
Providence spokeswoman said the grants helped make up for losses from
the coronavirus.
Those cash piles come from a mix of
sources: no-strings-attached private donations, income from investments
with hedge funds and private equity firms, and any profits from treating
patients. Some chains, like Providence, also run their own
venture-capital firms to invest their cash in cutting-edge start-ups.
The investment portfolios often generate billions of dollars in annual
profits, dwarfing what the hospitals earn from serving patients.
Many
of these hospital groups, including Providence, are set up as
nonprofits, which generally don’t have to pay federal taxes on their
billions of dollars of income.
By contrast, hospitals
that serve low-income patients often have only enough cash on hand to
finance a few weeks of their operations.
After the
CARES Act was passed in March, hospital industry lobbyists reached out
to senior Health and Human Services officials to discuss how the money
would be distributed.
Representatives of the American
Hospital Association, a lobbying group for the country’s largest
hospitals, communicated with Alex M. Azar II, the department secretary,
and Eric Hargan, the deputy secretary overseeing the funds, said Tom
Nickels, a lobbyist for the group. Chip Kahn, president of the
Federation of American Hospitals, which lobbies on behalf of for-profit
hospitals, said he, too, had frequent discussions with the agency.
The
department then devised formulas to quickly dispense tens of billions
of dollars to thousands of hospitals — and those formulas favored large,
wealthy institutions.
One formula based allotments on how much money a hospital
collected from Medicare last year. Another was based on a hospital’s
revenue. While Health and Human Services also created separate pots of
funding for rural hospitals and those hit especially hard by the
coronavirus, the department did not take into account each hospital’s
existing financial resources.
“This simple formula used
the data we had on hand at that time to get relief funds to the largest
number of health care facilities and providers as quickly as possible,”
said Caitlin B. Oakley, a spokeswoman for the department. “While other approaches were considered, these would have taken much longer to implement.”
Hospitals
that serve a greater proportion of wealthier, privately insured
patients got twice as much relief as those focused on low-income
patients with Medicaid or no coverage at all, according to a study this month by the Kaiser Family Foundation.
“If
you ever hear a hospital complaining they don’t have enough money, see
if they have a venture fund,” said Niall Brennan, president of the
nonprofit Health Care Cost Institute and a former senior Medicare
official. “If you’ve got play money, you’re fine.”
In a letter this month
to the Department of Health and Human Services, two House committee
chairmen said the Trump administration appeared to be disregarding
Congress’s intent in how it was distributing the aid.
“The
level of funding appears to be completely disconnected from need,”
wrote the two Democrats, Representatives Frank Pallone Jr. of New Jersey
and Richard E. Neal of Massachusetts.
It is the latest
instance in which enormous and hastily enacted federal bailout programs
have benefited those who don’t appear to need the money. A package of
$170 billion in federal tax breaks, for example, will go overwhelmingly
to many of the country’s richest people and biggest companies. A
program to rescue small businesses initially directed hundreds of
millions of dollars in loans to publicly traded companies while many smaller firms were frozen out.
That pattern is repeating in the hospital rescue program.
For example, HCA Healthcare and Tenet Healthcare — publicly traded chains with billions of dollars in reserves and large credit lines from banks — together received more than $1.5 billion in federal funds.
For example, HCA Healthcare and Tenet Healthcare — publicly traded chains with billions of dollars in reserves and large credit lines from banks — together received more than $1.5 billion in federal funds.
An
HCA spokesman said the aid didn’t cover the expected lost revenue and
higher expenses caused by the coronavirus, while a Tenet spokeswoman
said the pandemic had suppressed the company’s profits.
The Cleveland Clinic got $199 million. Last year it had so much
money on hand — its $7 billion in cash helped generate $1.2 billion in
investment profits — that it paid investment advisers $28 million to
manage the fortune.
Angela Kiska, a Cleveland Clinic
spokeswoman, said the federal grants had “helped to partially offset the
significant losses in operating revenue due to Covid-19, while we
continue to provide care to patients in our communities.” The Cleveland
Clinic sent caregivers to hospitals in Detroit and New York as they were
flooded with coronavirus patients, she added.
The St.
Louis-based Ascension Health, which operates 150 hospitals nationwide,
has received at least $211 million from Health and Human Services. The
company, with $15.5 billion in cash, operates a venture capital fund and
an investment advisory firm that helps other companies manage their
money.
Even if Ascension stopped generating any revenue
whatsoever — a doomsday scenario — it would have enough cash to fully
operate for nearly eight months.
Nick Ragone, a spokesman for Ascension, said the federal funds
“facilitated our ability to serve our communities during this
unprecedented time.” He said Ascension had not furloughed or laid off
any workers and wouldn’t do so for “as long as possible.”
Critics
argue that hospitals with vast financial resources should not be
getting federal funds. “If you accumulated $18 billion and you are a
not-for-profit hospital system, what’s it for if other than a reserve
for an emergency?” said Dr. Robert Berenson, a physician and a health
policy analyst for the Urban Institute, a Washington research group.
Hospitals that serve poorer patients typically have thinner reserves to draw on.
Even before the coronavirus, roughly 400 hospitals in rural America were at risk of closing, said Alan Morgan, the chief executive of the National Rural Hospital Association. On average, the country’s 2,000 rural hospitals had enough cash to keep their doors open for 30 days.
Even before the coronavirus, roughly 400 hospitals in rural America were at risk of closing, said Alan Morgan, the chief executive of the National Rural Hospital Association. On average, the country’s 2,000 rural hospitals had enough cash to keep their doors open for 30 days.
Many
hospitals that primarily serve low-income people have received federal
grants that their executives say may not be enough to see them through
the current crisis.
At St. Claire HealthCare, the
largest rural hospital system in eastern Kentucky, the number of
surgeries dropped 88 percent during the pandemic — depriving the
hospital of a crucial revenue source. Looking to stanch the financial
damage, it furloughed employees and canceled some vendor contracts. The
$3 million the hospital received from the federal government in April
will cover two weeks of payroll, said Donald H. Lloyd II, the health
system’s chief executive.
“This is just a Band-Aid,” Mr. Lloyd said.
The Harris Health System, which operates two hospitals in Houston, treats mostly uninsured patients. In a good year, it has a 1 percent profit margin, said Esmaeil Porsa, its chief executive.
The Harris Health System, which operates two hospitals in Houston, treats mostly uninsured patients. In a good year, it has a 1 percent profit margin, said Esmaeil Porsa, its chief executive.
The
system has lost about $43 million in patient revenue during the
pandemic, Mr. Porsa said. So far, it has received about a quarter of
that in federal grants. It is unclear how it will make up the shortfall.
“I
know there are hospitals out there that have some God-awful amount of
money in reserve,” Mr. Porsa said. “We are not that, and we will never
be that. Whatever cash we have we’re going to pour into services.”
That
is not how things work at the Providence Health System, which in some
ways resembles a Silicon Valley powerhouse as much as a health care
company. Providence owns 51 hospitals, including Swedish Medical Center
in Seattle, and 1,100 clinics in California, Texas and others states.
Even
with the federal grants, Providence lost $179 million in April, said
Melissa Tizon, a company spokeswoman. The bailout money has helped the
company avoid laying off staff or reducing their pay.
“Remember, the pandemic isn’t over,” Ms. Tizon said. “We need to be financially stable for the next possible wave.”
But Providence’s financial stability does not appear to be in jeopardy.
The hospital network has nearly $12 billion in cash reserves. It has invested that money in hedge funds, private equity firms and real estate ventures.
The hospital network has nearly $12 billion in cash reserves. It has invested that money in hedge funds, private equity firms and real estate ventures.
It also oversees two venture capital
funds that manage about $300 million on behalf of the health care chain.
The venture funds do deals alongside some of the country’s
highest-profile investment firms, including Kleiner Perkins and Carlyle.
Last
year, Providence’s portfolio of investments generated about $1.3
billion in profits, far exceeding the profits from its hospital
operations. Like other nonprofits, Providence generally does not owe
federal taxes on its earnings.
In 2018, Providence paid its chief executive, Dr. Rod Hochman, more than $10 million.
That would be enough to finance about a month of operations at the St. Claire hospitals in Kentucky.
Kitty Bennett contributed research.
https://www.nytimes.com/2020/05/25/business/hospitals-bailout-billions.html?action=click&module=Top%20Stories&pgtype=Homepage
That would be enough to finance about a month of operations at the St. Claire hospitals in Kentucky.
Kitty Bennett contributed research.
https://www.nytimes.com/2020/05/25/business/hospitals-bailout-billions.html?action=click&module=Top%20Stories&pgtype=Homepage
The Best Way to Ensure Unemployed Workers Get Health Care? Pay for It Through Medicare
There's only one group that benefits handsomely from the COBRA proposal: The health insurance industry.
by -
The coronavirus pandemic should leave no doubt that employer-based health care coverage puts millions of people at risk of going without needed care when they lose their jobs. The Medicare Crisis program, a bill in Congress proposed by Representative Pramila Jayapal (D-WA), would guarantee access to care for millions of newly unemployed Americans.
A new report from economists at the University of Amherst, PERI, reveals that Ms. Jayapal’s bill, which uses federal dollars to pay for coverage through Medicare, is both a less costly and more effective way to help unemployed workers than the proposal that House Speaker Nancy Pelosi (D-CA) is promoting, which would buy them continuing health insurance coverage through COBRA.
The Medicare Crisis program offers far more generous benefits than the COBRA proposal, the Worker Health Coverage Protection Act. Still, according to the economists at PERI, the cost to the federal government of the Medicare Crisis program based on coverage for 38.7 million people is $22.3 billion less than the full cost of care under the COBRA proposal, $47.5 billion vs. $69.8 billion for three months of coverage.
"Jayapal's bill, which uses federal dollars to pay
for coverage through Medicare, is both a less costly and more effective
way to help unemployed workers than the proposal that House Speaker
Nancy Pelosi is promoting, which would buy them continuing health
insurance coverage through COBRA."
The Medicare Crisis program also covers a lot more people in need of
insurance than the COBRA proposal. The Medicare Crisis program covers
all recently unemployed workers and their families who lack health
insurance, around 57.7 million people. The Worker Health Care Protection
Act covers only recently unemployed workers and their families who
previously had health insurance through their jobs, around 38.7 million
people.Yet, it costs nearly the same amount to provide three months of care for 18.9 million more unemployed workers and their families under the Medicare Crisis program than under the COBRA proposal. And, only under the Medicare Crisis program would the unemployed workers not face financial barriers to care. Care costs $70 billion for 57.6 million people under the Medicare Crisis program. Care costs $69.8 billion for 38.7 million people under the COBRA proposal, assuming that these unemployed workers could afford to pay $10.3 billion in out-of-pocket costs.
The Medicare Crisis program removes almost all barriers to care. By relying on Medicare to cover care for unemployed workers, it gives them unrestricted access to health care providers wherever they are in the United States. Virtually all doctors and hospitals participate in Medicare.
The Medicare Crisis program covers the full cost of COVID-19 care. And, it provides unemployed workers with coverage for all other medically necessary care with a cap on out-of-pocket costs at five percent of their income. Moreover, they would not have the hassle of seeking pre-authorizations for their care. Nor would they face delays and denials of care, as people with corporate health insurance so often do.
In stark contrast, the COBRA proposal pays people’s COBRA premiums, which allows them to continue their employer coverage. But, it comes with the same out-of-pocket costs and restrictions on the health care providers they can use. They would be limited to care from network doctors and hospitals.
"If the goal is to help unemployed workers, the
COBRA proposal makes little sense. Without a job, most unemployed
workers will struggle to afford out-of-pocket costs for their care. Many
will be forced to forgo needed care. And, it offers no benefit to
unemployed workers who did not previously have health insurance through
their employer."
The Medicare Crisis program is also far more equitable than the COBRA
proposal. Everyone who has lost their jobs gets federally-financed
access to high-quality care under the Medicare Crisis program. The COBRA
proposal discriminates against people who lost their jobs but did not
have health insurance or who had poor quality health insurance. It gives
people back the health care coverage they had, spending more on people
who had better health insurance coverage and less on people with worse
coverage.If the goal is to help unemployed workers, the COBRA proposal makes little sense. Without a job, most unemployed workers will struggle to afford out-of-pocket costs for their care. Many will be forced to forgo needed care. And, it offers no benefit to unemployed workers who did not previously have health insurance through their employer.
There’s one group that benefits handsomely from the COBRA proposal: The health insurance industry. It guarantees corporate insurers billions of premium dollars they would otherwise lose. But, by most accounts, the health insurance industry is already thriving as a result of the pandemic. It is spending far less on COVID-19 care than it would have been spending on the thousands of elective procedures that have been put on hold. Focus should be on guaranteeing Americans access to care, not on subsidizing a profitable industry.
Given the respective costs and benefits of the Medicare Crisis program and the COBRA program, it could not be more clear that the Medicare Crisis program is the most cost-effective and best solution to ensure unemployed workers get the care they need. For the health and well-being of working Americans, Congress should stand strongly behind it.
https://www.commondreams.org/views/2020/05/15/best-way-ensure-unemployed-workers-get-health-care-pay-it-through-medicare
‘The next crisis’: Up to 43 million Americans could lose health insurance due to pandemic, study shows
The pandemic "exposes a lot of the inadequacies in our system."
Become a powerful force for change
Because health insurance is tied to employment for about half the country—160 million people—as many as 43 million are expected to lose their health insurance due to the pandemic, according to a new report by the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation (RWJF) and the Urban Institute.
Analysts project that 43 million Americans could lose their insurance when the unemployment rate hits 20%. According to the Department of Labor, the current unemployment rate is 14.7%. Some economists estimate that between 19% and 23.6% of Americans are actually out of a job, including those who lost their jobs in the last two weeks and those who have not filed for jobless claims.
The pandemic “exposes a lot of the inadequacies in our system,” RWJF senior policy analyst Katherine Hempstead told The Guardian, adding that healthcare is “tied to employment for no real reason.”
On social media, Indiana congressional candidate Veronikka Ziol argued that there is a reason to link people’s ability to seek medical care to their ability to hold a job which offers health benefits—”It’s to hold a bargaining chip over the working-class’s head.”
“Do what we want for the pittance we’re paying, or you’re going to lose your healthcare,” Ziol wrote.
“This is why we need Medicare for All,” she added.
Last month, the Economic Policy Institute estimated that 12.7 million people had already lost their employer-based health insurance.
Of the Americans who lose insurance due to layoffs or furloughs, RWJF and the Urban Institute, an estimated seven million will remain uninsured—unable to access healthcare through Medicaid or COBRA, the law which allows Americans to pay for the health insurance they had through their previous employer—which can cost hundreds of dollars per month for individual coverage.
With millions expected to join the more than 27 million Americans who were uninsured before the pandemic, the RWJF and the Urban Institute raised concerns that many will avoid medical attention if they begin showing symptoms of the coronavirus, raising the risk of spreading the illness in their communities and making it more difficult for the country as a whole to combat the pandemic.
“The American healthcare financing system was not built to withstand the combined impact of a pandemic and a recession,” Dr. Adam Gaffney, the president of Physicians for a National Health Program, told The Guardian. “It’s inevitable that people will die because they can’t get the care they need, because of the looming recession.”
https://www.nationofchange.org/2020/05/11/the-next-crisis-up-to-43-million-americans-could-lose-health-insurance-due-to-pandemic-study-shows/
Fundamental health reform like ‘Medicare for All’ would help the labor marketJob loss claims are misleading, and substantial boosts to job quality are often overlooked
Fundamental health reform like “Medicare for All” would be a hugely ambitious policy undertaking with profound effects on the economy and the economic security of households in America. But despite oft-repeated claims of large-scale job losses, a national program that would guarantee health insurance for every American would not profoundly affect the total number of jobs in the U.S. economy. In fact, such reform could boost wages and jobs and lead to more efficient labor markets that better match jobs and workers. Specifically, it could:
- Boost wages and salaries by allowing employers to redirect money they are spending on health care costs to their workers’ wages.
- Increase job quality by ensuring that every job now comes bundled with a guarantee of health care—with the boost to job quality even greater among women workers, who are less likely to have employer-sponsored health care.
- Lessen the stress and economic shock of losing a job or moving between jobs by eliminating the loss of health care that now accompanies job losses and transitions.
- Support self-employment and small business development—which is currently super low in the U.S. relative to other rich countries—by eliminating the daunting loss of/cost of health care from startup costs.
- Inject new dynamism and adaptability into the overall economy by reducing “job lock”—with workers going where their skills and preferences best fit the job, not just to workplaces (usually large ones) that have affordable health plans.
- Produce a net increase in jobs as public spending boosts aggregate demand, with job losses in health insurance and billing administration being outweighed by job gains in provision of health care, including the expansion of long-term care.
Background: The need for fundamental health reform
Currently, despite the significant gains in health care coverage spurred by the passage of the Affordable Care Act (ACA) in 2010, roughly 23 million Americans between the ages of 19 and 64 are uninsured, and another 64 million are underinsured (Collins, Bhupal, and Doty 2019).1 In addition to problems with access, the American health care system also suffers from excess costs.2 While excess health care cost growth has slowed notably in the last decade, it would be prudent for policymakers to try to keep this cost growth in check with significant policy reforms rather than simply hoping for the best going forward. Some highly important health-related prices have begun rising rapidly in the very recent past. Insurance premiums, for example, rose 20% in 2019.3 Overall spending on prescription drugs rose more than 9% between the fourth quarter of 2018 and the fourth quarter of 2019—the largest year-over-year change since 2015.4Bivens 2018b provides data demonstrating that health spending in the U.S. is higher than in advanced peer countries and has risen faster over time—and yet continues to buy worse health outcomes. The higher and faster-growing spending of the United States is driven by faster growth of prices, not by growth in the volume of health care goods and services consumed. Further, international evidence shows that a key component of controlling cost growth is a strong public role in setting and negotiating the prices of health care goods and services.
A fundamental reform like Medicare for All (M4A) would make coverage universal. Further, by providing a counterweight to (or outright eliminating) the substantial market power that keeps prices high and that is currently wielded by many key players in the health care sector (e.g., insurance companies, drug companies, specialty physicians, and device makers), such a reform could also have great success in containing health care cost growth. This could in turn provide relief from many of the ways that rising health costs squeeze family incomes.
An underappreciated benefit of such a reform is that it would also lead to a much better functioning labor market in many areas. Job quality would increase, job switching would become less stressful, better “matches” between workers and employers would boost productivity, and small businesses would be much easier to launch.
Despite the fact that M4A could deliver these large benefits to efficient labor market functioning, the policy often comes under fire from critics making highly exaggerated claims about the potential job loss that could occur under such a reform. The grain of truth in some of the claims is that, like any productivity improvement, the adoption of a reform like M4A would require the redeployment of workers from one sector (the health insurance and medical billing complex) to other sectors (mostly the delivery of health care). But there is little in the M4A-induced redeployment of workers that would greatly stress the American labor market over and above the uncertainty and churn that characterizes this labor market every year. Smart policy could make this redeployment eminently manageable for those workers who would be required to make the transition.
This brief highlights some labor market implications of M4A and critically examines claims that large job losses in the health insurance and billing administration sectors would make M4A an undesirable policy.
Health reform as labor market policy: Key effects for workers
Fundamental reforms like M4A could greatly aid labor market outcomes for U.S. workers. The most obvious benefits would be higher wages and salaries, increased availability of good jobs, reduced stress during spells of job loss, better “matches” between workers and employers, and greater opportunity to start small businesses.Higher cash wages and salaries
Medicare for All could increase wages and salaries for U.S. workers by reducing employers’ costs for health insurance—freeing up fiscal space to invest in wages instead. The share of total annual compensation paid to American employees in the form of health insurance premiums rather than wages and salaries rose from 1.1% in 1960 to 4.2% in 1979 to 8.4% in 2018.5 If this post-1960 increase had been only half as large—and employers had spent the health cost savings on wages and salaries—the take-home wages of American workers would have been almost $400 billion higher in 2018.6 Given that the share of total compensation spoken for by health insurance premiums is starting from a high base today, any reform that managed to slow the excess growth of health spending going forward would go a long way in making space for faster growth of cash compensation.7Increased availability of ‘good jobs’
Medicare for All could increase job quality substantially by making all jobs “good” jobs in terms of health insurance coverage and by increasing the potential for higher wages. While the definition of a “good job” is always going to be a bit imprecise, the vast majority of U.S. workers would say that a good job is one that pays decent wages and that also provides the health insurance coverage and retirement income benefits that most of today’s workers can only reliably access through employment. Nearly half of jobs fail this test on account of health care coverage alone: In 2016, 46.9% of workers held jobs in which their employer made no contributions to the workers’ health care; for workers in the middle fifth of the wage distribution, 42.9% held jobs in which the employer made no contribution to their health care (EPI 2017).By making health coverage universal and delinking from employment, M4A would make it far easier for employers to offer good jobs in this regard, as every job would now be accompanied by guaranteed health care coverage. Further, as noted above, wages and salaries would have substantial room to grow if health care costs were taken off of the backs of employers. Schmitt and Jones (2013) estimate the share of good jobs—jobs that clear a specified wage floor8 and provide health and retirement coverage—in overall employment each year between 1979 and 2011. They then look at various policy changes that would boost this share. They find that providing universal health coverage would boost the probability that any given job in the economy is a good job by almost 20%—and that’s even before any potential boost to the share of jobs that are good jobs coming from cash wage increases provided as employers shed health care costs.9 The boost to job quality from making health coverage universal would be even greater for women workers, as women are currently less likely to receive employer-sponsored health insurance benefits from their own employers.10
Less damaging spells of joblessness
Medicare for All could make job losses and transitions less stressful by delinking employment and access to health insurance, emulating the universal access to health care offered by our rich country peers. The U.S. is unique among the rich countries of the world in how much it ties crucial social benefits—like health insurance and retirement income—to specific jobs. Hacker (2002) has referred to this arrangement as the “divided welfare state,” with some Americans having relatively full access to health and retirement security while others have access to virtually none, all based on the specific jobs they have. This makes some jobs in the U.S. economy especially valuable, and hence especially damaging to lose. Manufacturing workers without a college degree, for example, likely incur enormous income and social benefits losses in the event of job loss stemming from either automation or trade. The ability of universal, public social benefits to make individual job losses less damaging has been long recognized by social scientists (see, for example, Estevez-Abe, Iversen, and Soskice 2001).Smooth job transitions contribute to economic dynamism by helping ensure that vacancies are filled quickly by appropriate workers and that unemployed workers can quickly find new jobs that make good use of their skills. Smooth job transitions will also be an important components of meeting crucial policy goals such as mitigating greenhouse gas emissions with wholesale changes in how energy is created. Policies that make job transitions easier and inspire less resistance from workers should be encouraged. Fundamental health reform that, like M4A, guarantees access to insurance regardless of one’s current job status is a key part of making such transitions easier.
Better labor market matches between workers and employers
Medicare for All could decrease inefficient “job lock” and boost small business creation and voluntary self-employment. Making health insurance universal and delinked from employment widens the range of economic options for workers and leads to better matches between workers’ skills and interests and their jobs. The boost to small business creation and self-employment would be particularly useful, as the United States is a laggard in both relative to advanced economy peers.Substantial evidence indicates that our current system of employer-sponsored insurance (ESI) creates significant “job lock”—a condition in which workers who don’t want to lose their current ESI stay in their current jobs rather than make transitions that would better meet their needs. In a comprehensive review of this literature, Baker (2015) finds:
The likely range of a job-lock effect is a reduction in turnover—the rate at which people leave jobs—of 15–25 percent among workers with EPHI [employer-provided health insurance, or ESI]. With normal turnover for prime-age workers (people ages 25–54) in the range of 15–20 percent per year, this job-lock effect implies a reduction in annual turnover of around 4 percentage points among prime-age workers with [employer-provided health insurance, or ESI].Making employment decisions based on access to ESI rather than on other criteria—such as work–life balance, cash wages, and commuting distance—can lead to employment “matches” that are less productive and that decrease overall worker welfare relative to job choices that are not constrained by the availability of health insurance.
More small-business formation
Despite policymakers’ frequent claims that they seek to support small businesses in the U.S. economy, the United States has a notably small share of small-business employment relative to our rich country peers. In 2018, for example, the U.S. was dead-last among the members of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) in its share of self-employment, at just 6.3% of employment. Countries that are frequently portrayed in U.S. business reporting as being choked by regulation—like Spain, France, and Germany—have far higher shares of self-employment, at 16.0%, 11.7%, and 9.9%, respectively (OECD 2020).Besides a low share of self-employment, the U.S. also had significantly lower shares of overall employment in small businesses, across nearly all industrial sectors. The latest OECD data show that the U.S. share of employment in enterprises with fewer than 50 employees is lower than in any other country except for Russia (OECD 2018, Figure 7). In an earlier overview of trends in employment by firm size, Schmitt and Lane (2009) highlight how health care policy plays two key roles in potentially explaining cross-country trends. First, because health care is nearly universally provided in other rich countries, workers choosing to start their own businesses in those countries do not face a cost confronting would-be entrepreneurs in the U.S.: the loss of ESI. Second, small businesses in the U.S. are at a distinct disadvantage in recruiting employees because the cost of providing health care coverage is significantly higher for small companies.11
Employment effects of fundamental health reform: gains in health care, losses in insurance and billing—with likely economywide net job gains from rising economic demand
Like all positive productivity gains, Medicare for All would be more likely to increase the total number of jobs in the U.S. economy, even as health reform leads to the redeployment of workers from some sectors and into others.Despite the many labor market benefits of fundamental health reform like M4A, many critics have claimed that such reform would lead to a loss of jobs. This claim is misleading. One small grain of truth to it is that the universal provision of health insurance would allow people who would strongly prefer not to work (or not to work full time), but who have remained in their current jobs in order to retain health insurance, to be free to quit. This type of voluntary reduction in labor supply following a health reform would be strongly welfare-improving. For example, the ACA was clearly associated with a large increase in parents with young children transitioning to part-time work (see Jørgensen and Baker 2014). To the degree this occurred because these parents no longer needed to work full time to obtain ESI, and they preferred spending more time with their children for reasons of work–life balance, it should be seen as a clear win for the policy.
Generally, people expressing concern about job loss stemming from a policy are concerned about involuntary job loss that leads to a higher level of unemployment in the economy. Unemployment is almost entirely a function of the level of aggregate demand: spending by households, businesses, and governments.12 The effect of fundamental health reform on the level of aggregate demand depends in turn on the balance of increased public spending and the means of financing this spending. All else equal, more public spending will boost aggregate demand and create jobs, while higher taxes will reduce aggregate demand and restrain job growth. Further, the progressivity of taxes used to finance fundamental health reform will also condition its effect on aggregate demand. The more progressive the taxes that finance health reform, the less they will drag on job growth. Increased public spending combined with progressive tax increases would almost certainly boost the level of aggregate demand and lead to lower unemployment, all else equal.
While the overall number of jobs and the level of unemployment in the economy is largely a macroeconomic issue determined by aggregate demand, claims that fundamental health reform like M4A will lead to job loss sometimes sound plausible because it is easy to envision the specific jobs that might be displaced: jobs in the health insurance and billing administration sectors. But these job displacements would be balanced by likely job gains in other sectors—most particularly in health care delivery. The health insurance coverage expansions of M4A will boost demand for health care goods and services, and workers will need to be hired to meet this demand.
Job losses in the health insurance and billing administration sectors
A recent analysis of the economic effects of M4A (Pollin et al. 2018) includes the projection that up to 1.8 million jobs in the health insurance and billing administration sector (the divisions of hospitals and doctors’ offices dedicated to administrative processing of bills and payments) could be made redundant. These potential 1.8 million lost jobs are frequently presented as if they constitute the net employment effect of M4A.13 This is a deeply flawed misrepresentation of Pollin and his colleagues’ work. In fact, their estimates are a gross (not net) measure of job displacement or “churn”—the regular process of workers starting and leaving jobs during the course of their work lives. Relative to the scale of other gross measures of job churn, the churn associated with M4A is not large.It is true that one source of cost savings from the introduction of M4A is the reduced demand for insurance and billing administration. In turn, this reduced demand would shift employment out of these sectors. This could certainly cause challenges and economic distress for the workers within these sectors who are directly affected. But for some perspective, it is worth noting that 21.5 million workers were laid off in 2018 (BLS 2020b). If the 1.8 million workers that Pollin et al. (2018) identify as potentially being displaced by M4A were forced to transition over the four-year phase-in commonly identified with M4A plans, this would increase the national rate of layoffs by about 2%. It is also worth noting that even within just the finance and insurance sectors, there have been 1.7 million layoffs in the past four years (BLS 2020b). And yet it’s safe to say that very few people even in the business press have made any note of this. This is not a shock: Our economy generates a huge amount of job churn every year. This churn is the hallmark of growth in productivity—getting more economic output with fewer inputs. While productivity growth can indeed put downward pressure on jobs in the sector experiencing it directly, Autor and Salomons (2018) demonstrate that productivity gains within a given sector strongly boost job growth in other sectors, as the savings to households and businesses stemming from enhanced productivity increase purchasing power that supports demand for these other sectors’ outputs.
If workers in the insurance or billing administration sectors were particularly hard-pressed for reemployment prospects because of geographic isolation or low average levels of educational credentials, their displacement might pose particular concern to policymakers. But employment in the health insurance and billing administration sectors is not particularly geographically concentrated,14 and Pollin et al. (2018) show that 56.5% of workers in these sectors have a four-year college degree or more education, a far greater share than the overall labor force (in 2018, 37.6% of workers had a four-year degree or more education, according to EPI 2020b).
Substantial likely job gains in the health care sector
While it may seem counterintuitive, fundamental health reform like M4A is almost guaranteed to substantially expand employment in the health care sector overall, even taking reduced billing administration employment into account. Often people hear that fundamental reform is aimed at cost containment and then imagine that part of this cost containment will take the form of fewer jobs providing health care, but this is not necessarily the case. As noted before, the U.S. is an outlier in terms of how much it spends on health care, but its health care workforce as a share of the total workforce is not out of line with shares in other countries. For example, in 2017 the health care workforce in the U.S. was equal to 13.4% of the overall workforce, while the share averaged 12.9% in the 20 other richest OECD countries.15 Additionally, seven of these other countries had health care workforce shares equal to or higher than the U.S.’s 13.4%.16Pollin et al. (2018) estimate that expanded access to health care could increase demand for health services by up to $300 billion annually. Given the current level of health spending and employment, this would translate into increased demand for 2.3 million full-time-equivalent workers in providing healthcare.17 Obviously all of the workers displaced from the health insurance and billing administration sectors could not necessarily transition into these jobs seamlessly, but well over 10% of workers in the health insurance sector, for example, are actually in health care occupations (e.g., they are doctors or nurses).18
Further, several M4A plans have provisions to pay for long-term care services. Reinhard et al. (2019) have estimated that in 2018, Americans provided roughly 34 billion hours in unpaid long-term care. If this care was divided up among full-time paid workers, it would require 17 million new positions. Of course, not all of this currently unpaid care would be converted into paid positions in the job market. But if even 10% of unpaid care translated into new jobs, it would create enough new demand for workers to essentially offset the displacement of workers in the health insurance and billing administration sectors.
The upshot: M4A creates a small amount of manageable churn but increases the overall demand for labor and boosts job quality
The job challenge relating to a fundamental health reform is managing a relatively small increase in job churn during an initial phase-in period. Most Medicare for All plans explicitly recognize and account for the costs of providing these workers the elements of a just transition. As noted previously, this sort of just transition is far easier when health care is universally provided.Besides this challenge, the effect of fundamental reform like M4A on the labor market would be nearly uniformly positive. The effect of a fundamental reform like M4A on aggregate demand is almost certainly positive and will therefore boost the demand for labor. The number of jobs spurred by increased demand for new health care spending (including long-term care) will certainly be larger than the number displaced by realizing efficiencies in the health insurance and billing administration sectors.
Finally, the introduction of fundamental health reform like M4A—particularly reform that substantially delinks health care provision from specific jobs—would greatly aid how the labor market functions for typical working Americans. Take-home cash pay would increase, job quality would improve, labor market transitions could be eased for employers and made less damaging to workers, and a greater range of job opportunities could be considered by workers. The increased flexibility to leave jobs should lead to more productive “matches” between workers and employers, and small businesses and self-employment could increase.
Fundamental health reform would benefit typical American families in all sorts of ways. Importantly, contrary to claims that such reform might be bad for jobs, this reform could substantially improve how labor markets function for these families.
https://www.epi.org/publication/medicare-for-all-would-help-the-labor-market/
No comments:
Post a Comment